Politics,Climate Change and Sundry issues

Politics,Climate Change and Sundry issues
for website listing my blogs : http://winstonclosepolitics.com

Sunday 4 May 2014

Revolutionising tax and decreasing inequality

Revolutionising tax and decreasing inequality

Revolutionising tax and decreasing inequality





The tax and other laws of Australia are currently being
designed to increase rather than limit the inequality between rich and
poor citizens and the Abbott Government's budget looks set to continue
widening this disparity, writes Bill Mavropoulos.




The question of fairness in our tax system was brought to the fore with the handing down of the Federal Commission of Audit (COA) on last week. 



One of the recommendations was cutting the Federal income tax rate
and allowing each of the States to set their own levy on top of it.
Instead of refuting this and many similar ideas from the COA directly,
it is perhaps better to examine their policies with reference to the
current global tax debate on addressing inequality sparked by a French
economist who is quickly becoming notorious.




The world is indeed a funny place. Had someone suggested a few months ago that the number one best seller on Amazon
would be a book on tax and wealth distribution, they would have been
laughed out of the office. It would seem however that tax is finally
(and deservedly) cool. We can thank the unlikely hero who gave rise to
these circumstances, Thomas Piketty. His book Capital in the Twenty-First Century has catapulted him into ‘rockstar’ status.




The book is the product of fifteen years
of research by Piketty and a team of economists into income and wealth
inequality in the US and a host of other developed economies around the
world.




The popularity of the book is even more unlikely when you consider
that Piketty was trying to prove something that most sensible people
already know — that the inequality between rich and poor people is
increasing. Piketty’s team spent untold hours compiling and making sense
of historic tax data from multiple jurisdictions to prove this point.
Perhaps then, the reason for the fanfare is what he does once he answers
this obvious question — he goes out on a limb and tells the world how
to go about fixing the problem.




The book outlines how our current economic systems tend to
concentrate wealth into the hands of a comparatively small group of
people.




Briefly, Piketty provides a rate of return on wealth based on his
meticulous and painstakingly gathered tax data. At its simplest, wealth
could be thought of as the sum of assets less liabilities. Once he
worked out the rate of growth for wealth, he compared it with the growth
rate of a given economy to make his point — that where the rate of
return on wealth is much greater than the growth rate of an economy,
wealth will tend to be concentrated in fewer and fewer hands. Because of
the compounding effect of wealth, it becomes more and more difficult
through hard work and innovation to break into this wealthy group in our
society.






In true economist style, Piketty doesn’t see wealth inequality as
necessarily a bad thing because if it is difficult to attain wealth,
this creates an economic incentive for people to work harder, which
increases the growth rate of the economy. The problem arises when it
becomes so difficult to become wealthy that this economic incentive is
removed. In other words, people stop striving to become wealthy because
they perceive that this is out of their reach. This has the effect of
limiting growth and causing the destabilisation of an economy, instead
of encouraging economic growth.




The book proposes a radical solution to this problem.



According to Piketty, a global tax on wealth would effectively
redistribute some of the growth from the net assets of the wealthy
thereby reducing inequality. In other words, if the rate of return on
wealth is decreased to bring it closer to the growth rate of the
economy, the gap between the rich and poor will reduce, which in turn
will drive economic growth.




Current taxes focus on taxing income earned in a given year.



What Piketty proposes is a tax that is levied upon ‘net wealth’
instead. The argument is that people with more wealth should be subject
to a greater tax burden to bring the rate of return on their wealth into
line with the growth rate of the economy. The wealth is effectively
redistributed to less wealthy people who are more likely to spend wealth
(rather than hoard it) on goods and services thereby increasing
economic growth.




Predictably, right leaning commentators are accusing Thomas Piketty of Communist ideals to rival those of Karl Marx and discount his idea to fix this problem.



Considering these commentators do not have painstakingly-gathered empirical research into tax data spanning over a century
to back their claims, as well as proven economic modelling and
experience, their credibility is seriously questionable. The accuracy of
Piketty’s claims about the growing gap between rich and poor is plain
to see in all the developed economies, especially the United States,
where middle class wealth has stagnated (and even gone backwards) whilst
the wealth of the richest has grown exponentially.






Australia and inequality



An interesting thing happens when you view the Australian tax system
within the prism of Piketty’s work. Take for instance the humble 50 per
cent discount on capital gains.




This tax concession applies to capital assets by shielding half of
the gains made in this way from tax. This means the rate of return on
capital gains (which, as an already-held asset, we can view as wealth)
is artificially higher because half of it escapes taxation.




Wages, on the other hand, are wholly subject to tax.



The disparity of treatment between capital gains and wages and is
rarely questioned by the majority of the public — or, in fact, by tax
professionals and government, for that matter.




It doesn’t stop there; deceased estates
have long enjoyed concessional tax treatment that allows the majority
of capital assets (or wealth) acquired through inheritance to escape
taxation entirely.




Then, lastly and perhaps most obviously, we continue to provide
superannuation concessions that are increasingly more lucrative for
superannuation funds that hold greater amounts of wealth, particularly
for Australians over preservation age.




The point is that this trend of shielding the assets (or wealth) of
the rich while increasing the burden of taxation on the poor is still
our current tax policy direction. This can be illustrated with a few
more examples.




Treasurer Joe Hockey hints at increasing the revenue brought in by the GST, a consumption based tax.



On the face of it, this seems like a reasonable and efficient way to
generate revenue for the Australian budget. What is left unsaid is that
the poor disproportionately bear the economic burden of increases in consumption taxes, because proportionately they spend more on consumption.




So, while this tax is efficient in its collection, it may actually
impede growth by reducing the income of the groups most likely to spend
their wealth. The further effect will be a widening of the gap between
poor and rich as the rate of return on wealth would not be materially
affected by a consumption tax, but economic growth through a reduction
in poor people’s purchasing power may be.




A $6 co-payment to see a doctor suggested by the Government – let alone the $15 suggested
by the Commission of Audit – again places more of a burden on the less
well-off Australians and reduces their access to health care.






The government argument that revenue may be needed to fund healthcare
is sensible. However, why was there no discussion around partially
removing the concession on the Medicare levy surcharge
for taxpayers with private health insurance to plug this gap instead?
These taxpayers earn over $84,000 meaning this measure would target
wealthy people while arguably being more politically sensible than a
debt levy, as it represents the reduction of a tax concession rather
than the imposition of a new tax.




The mining tax is another example.



It was watered down to the point of not collecting any meaningful
revenue from super profits earned by companies extracting mineral wealth
from Australia and is slated to be removed altogether, along with vital
small business tax concessions. The controllers of these companies are
indisputably wealthy.




Viewed in the context of Piketty’s work, now that a number of mines
are in production, rather than the construction phase, does it not make
more sense to give this tax the teeth Dr Ken Henry
intended it to have? This toughening up would impose a tax on the super
profits of the wealthy, reducing the return that they can garner from
their wealth, whilst simultaneously compensating the Australian public
for giving up these scarce resources.




The tax and other laws of Australia are currently being designed to
increase rather than limit the inequality between rich and poor
citizens.




In light of Piketty’s important book and out of the ideals of common
sense and social justice, Australia should provide a constructive
contribution to this global debate. Even where these ideas are rejected
out of hand, the Government, when wrestling with its ideology, would do
well to heed the words of Aristotle:




“It is the mark of an educated mind to be able to entertain a thought without accepting it.”






Bill Mavropoulos is a tax specialist with Taxpayers
Australia Inc — an independent non-for-profit advocacy group not
affiliated with any political party. You can follow Bill on Twitter @VMavropoulos. You can follow Tapayers Australia @TaxpayersAU.


No comments:

Post a Comment